What’s stopping Europe?
By Allan H. Meltzer
Professor of Political Economy at the Tepper School, Carnegie
Mellon University, and Distinguished Visiting Fellow at the Hoover
Institution
On a recent visit to Greece, French President François Hollande
declared that Europe's decline was over, and urged French companies
to invest in Greece. Bad advice. French production costs are high,
but Greek costs are higher. Despite the considerable decline in
Greek (and Italian and Spanish) real GDP since 2007, adjustment is
far from complete.
In fact, one would be hard pressed to find broad agreement with
Hollande's assessment anywhere in Europe. Before the recent Italian
election, financial markets showed signs of optimism, encouraged by
the European Central Bank's policy of guaranteeing eurozone
members' sovereign debt, expanding its balance sheet, and lowering
interest rates. Bondholders gain when interest rates fall. But
unemployment continues to rise in the heavily indebted southern
countries, and output continues to lag behind Germany and other
northern European countries.
The main reason for the lag is not simply low demand or large
debts. There is a vast difference between unit labor costs - real
wages adjusted for productivity - in Germany and in the heavily
indebted southern countries. When the crisis began, production
costs in Greece were about 30% higher than in Germany, so Greece
exported very little and imported very much. Production costs in
other heavily indebted countries were 20-25% higher than in
Germany.
Growth will not resume until production costs in the indebted
countries decline, which requires either a substantial permanent
increase in productivity, a reduction in real wages, or both. While
some adjustment has occurred, much of the change is not permanent.
Austerity reduced the number of employed workers, particularly
those with low skill and productivity levels. But gains in measured
productivity growth from this source are not permanent changes, so
a large part of the reported reductions in unit labor costs are
temporary.
Indeed, major cost differences remain. In Greece, the private
sector has been forced to adjust, but the government failed to keep
its promise to reduce public employment. That will prolong
excessive government spending, and deficit targets will not be met
on a sustained basis. Large reductions in public-sector wages
brought down the primary deficit, but employment maintenance lowers
productivity, raises costs, and delays adjustment.
In Italy, former Prime Minister Mario Monti's government undertook
some reforms, but it continued to support unions and corporate
monopolies. And Italy's parliament rejected many of Monti's
proposed reductions in government spending. Labor and many product
markets remain closed, despite the urgent need to increase
competition, lower production costs, and raise productivity.
After five years of slow growth and rising unemployment, voters in
other indebted countries, like Italians (and French voters before
them), are likely to reject additional spending reductions, tax
increases, and further painful deregulation. Europe must find more
effective policies that reduce production costs toward German
levels.
The economic historian Harold James has shown in a recent book that
in the 40 years of negotiations leading to the adoption of the
common currency, all of the problems that now beset the eurozone
were discussed repeatedly. Everyone understood that a monetary
union would require enforceable fiscal and banking rules. But such
rules were never adopted.
Before the euro, countries adjusted misaligned production costs by
devaluing or revaluing their exchange rates. Fiscal austerity is a
poor substitute. It works slowly, if at all, because elected
governments are often reluctant to implement their promises - and
may not feel bound by those of previous administrations (especially
if they owe their victory to voters who are rebelling against years
of belt-tightening with no evidence of renewed growth). Likewise,
politicians are reluctant to adopt deregulation that eliminates
state-sponsored special privileges.
For several years, I have proposed a policy that combines growth
and fiscal rectitude. Let all the heavily indebted southern
European countries jointly agree to join a weak euro, which would
float against the stronger northern euro. When the weak euro
reduces the heavily indebted countries' production costs by 20-25%,
they can rejoin the "hard" euro if they accept fiscal reforms that
are subject to approval by the European Commission (and thus by the
hard-euro creditor countries). After all, a fixed exchange rate or
common currency requires limits on fiscal independence.
The Italian election sent a message. After five years of decline in
living standards, voters oppose more austerity and further
retrenchment without growth. Restoring a sound euro requires
policies that revive growth, rein in government spending, and
reform heavily regulated labor and product markets.
Copyrights: Project Syndicate
Here we are to serve you with news right now. It does not cost much, but worth your attention.
Choose to support open, independent, quality journalism and subscribe on a monthly basis.
By subscribing to our online newspaper, you can have full digital access to all news, analysis, and much more.
You can also follow AzerNEWS on Twitter @AzerNewsAz or Facebook @AzerNewsNewspaper
Thank you!